Corporate Governance Bites

Continuing challenges to exclusive forum bylaw provisions – Lexology

An increasingly popular trend in recent years has been the adoption by Delaware public companies of an exclusive forum provision in their bylaws. An exclusive forum provision generally provides for the Delaware Court of Chancery to be the exclusive forum for certain disputes (including derivative actions, breach of fiduciary duty claims, claims arising pursuant
to the company’s charter or bylaws and other shareholder litigation) against the company — and prohibiting such suits in other jurisdictions. Expected benefits cited by companies of adopting exclusive forum bylaw provisions include decreased litigation costs, avoiding parallel litigation in multiple jurisdictions and the predictability of Delaware courts.

Shareowners generally oppose any exclusive forum provisions adopted by boards, unless put to a vote by shareowners.

 I did write a little about the movement toward exclusive forum provisions after Joe Grundfest urged companies to adopt them. See End to Forum Shopping and mocking nightmare post at after listening to Vice Chancellor Laster at a dinner event earlier this year.  See also Coordinated Attack on Exclusive Forum at theCorporateCounsel.net and Shareholders Sue Over Exclusive Forum Bylaws.

The Rise of the Superstar CEO: Are They The New American Idols? – Christopher Bennett, Governance Center Blog

ethics, This promotion of the charismatic approach inevitably led to the development of a “superstar system,” where there’s “… a highly skewed distribution of income, market share, and public attention …” – Rosen (1981). Rosen was actually writing about the movie business, but it seems that this quote is a fair description of the rise of CEO’s of major corporations. Just as a superstar’s name can sell movies, appointing a “superstar CEO” can make the stock price rise rapidly (in the short term, at least).

However, a charismatic, superstar CEO can also behave in ways which are antithetical to sound management (by imposing poor decisions) and good governance (by ignoring detail and compliance). And, where there is charismatic leadership, group members tend to view success in relation to their leaders’ opinion.

Bennett series of articles has been raising important issues. They are especially important because he is a compensation consultant and they have been in the lead in creating many of the problematic structures, in the first place.  Contrast with with Charles Elson’s recent study.

Executive Superstars, Peer Groups and Over-Compensation – Cause, Effect and Solution – Charles Elson

In setting the pay of their CEOs, boards invariably reference the pay of the executives at other enterprises in similar industries and of similar size and complexity. In what is described as “competitive benchmarking”, compensation levels are generally targeted to either the 50th, 75th, or 90th percentile. This process is alleged to provide an effective gauge of “market wages” which are necessary for executive retention…

By basing pay on primarily external comparisons, a separate regime which was untethered from the actual wage structures of the rest of the organization was established. Over time, these disconnected systems were bound to diverge. The pay of a chief executive officer, however, has a profound effect on the incentive structure throughout the corporate hierarchy. Rising pay thus has costs far greater than the amount actually transferred to the CEOs themselves…

We argue that: (I) theories of optimal market-based contracting are misguided in that they are predicated upon the chimerical notion of vigorous and competitive markets for transferable executive talent; (II) that even boards comprised of only the most faithful fiduciaries of shareholder interests will fail to reach an agreeable resolution to the compensation conundrum because of the unfounded reliance on the structurally malignant and unnecessary process of peer benchmarking; and, (III) that the solution lies in avoiding the mechanistic and arbitrary application of peer group data in arriving at executive compensation levels. Instead, independent and shareholder-conscious compensation committees must develop internally created standards of pay based on the individual nature of the organization concerned, its particular competitive environment and its internal dynamics.

Can the SEC fine itself? – Jon Lukomnik

Can the SEC fine itself for facilitating differential market access – in effect encouraging insider trading?

Perhaps it’s time for the SEC’s enforcement division to take a look inside the rabbit warren that is the SEC headquarters. Someone should point Robert Khuzami, the SEC’s head of enforcement, to the office of the Division of Trading and Markets. That division just approved allowing the New York Stock Exchange to profit by charging high frequency traders to “co-locate” their flash-crash causing computers at the NYSE’s data center. That, in turns, allows some investors to get price data before others.

Great to see Lukomnik back to blogging. His posts are tell stories of insight and wit.

Tim Smith: A Shareholder Advocate Who Means Business – CSWire.com

…Shareholder engagement makes for the most interesting part of Smith’s job. He listens carefully to his clients and then represents their concerns to the companies they invest in. It is in this role that he often finds himself on the doorstep of many companies, sometimes as a welcomed guest and other times not. It all depends on what he is asking a particular company to do, and whether or not they are open to dialogue…

Corporate governance practices are starting to change dramatically, in large part because of the pressure he and other investors have applied on companies, and because of the compelling business case that has been embraced by companies.

But today, Smith is focused on a different type of governance issue: Getting companies to be more transparent about their political contributions and lobbying activities.

Tim’s example, provided me with the inspiration to get involved 25-30 years ago. Let’s hope he continues to inspire at least another generation or two.

Wall Street’s First Corporate Governance Crisis: The Conspiracy Trials of 1826 – Eric Hilt

In July of 1826, several prominent Wall Street firms abruptly went bankrupt, amid scandalous revelations of fraudulent financial practices by their management. Although mostly forgotten today, these events represented a watershed in the early development of the corporation laws and investor protections governing Wall Street: in the aftermath of the scandals, New York State enacted an extensive package of legislation designed to protect the interests of investors. These statutes were some of the the very first of their kind, and had a lasting influence.

This paper analyzes the causes of the failures, and the evolution of the law in response. Almost 200 years later, scandal continues to by the main corporate governance driver. When will it be based on dreams and empirical research on the participatory salubrious institutions we actually want to create?

Preliminary 2013 Proxy Season Checklist (Updated 9/30/12) – Steve Quinlivan, Dodd-Frank.com

ItemStatus
Proxy Statements
1.  Compensation Consultant Conflicts of InterestNew S-K Item 407(e)(3)(iv) provides that if any compensation consultant has played a role in determining or recommending the amount or form of executive and director compensation, and the consultant’s work has raised any conflict of interest, then disclosure of the nature of the conflict and how the conflict is being addressed is required.  This rule is effective for any proxy or information statement for an annual meeting of shareholders at which directors will be elected occurring after January 1, 2013.Effective
2.  Say-on-pay exemption for smaller reporting companies:  Companies that qualified as “smaller reporting companies” as of January 21, 2011, including newly public companies that qualify as smaller reporting companies after January 21, 2011, are subject to the say-on-pay rules as of the first annual or other meeting of shareholders at which directors will be elected and for which the rules of the SEC require executive compensation disclosure pursuant to Item 402 of Regulation S-K occurring on or after January 21, 2013Effective

Many more items follow. Great resource from Steve Quinlivan.

Tech Credit Union members’ revolution! @stayacu – VoterMedia Democracy Blog

It’s reassuring to see that credit union members can wake up and say no when their directors seem to be acting against members’ interests. The members of Technology Credit Union in San Jose (California) recently voted down their board’s proposal to convert the credit union to a mutual savings bank.

Other co-op and credit union members losing their democratic systems of governance would do well to read Mark Latham’s paper We Want Our Co-ops Back and to implement a VoterMedia community program to reward coverage of governance activities so that members will be informed voters.

U.S. Income Inequality: It’s Worse Today Than It Was in 1774 – Jordan Weissmann, The Atlantic

On the eve of the Revolutionary War, wealth was distributed more evenly across the 13 colonies than anywhere else in the world that we have record of… The founding fathers evidently formed their ideas about democracy in a social context very different than our own, when distinctions of wealth simply weren’t as sharp.

Wouldn’t it be great to get back a little closer to the original model when wealth in America was not only distributed more equally but we were, on average, richer than those in any other country?

Top 1% Got 93% of Income Growth as Rich-Poor Gap Widened – Bloomberg

The earnings gap between rich and poor Americans was the widest in more than four decades in 2011, Census data show, surpassing income inequality previously reported in Uganda and Kazakhstan. The notion that each generation does better than the last — one aspect of the American Dream — has been challenged by evidence that average family incomes fell last decade for the first time since World War II.

What made America great during several decades after WWII was that most of the productivity gains went to the middle class as income.  Hedrick Smith’s Who Stole the American Dream? gathers some of the relevant research. From 1945 to the mid-1970s the productivity of American workers rose 96.8% and workers average pay rose 95%, almost identical. They were sharing in the nation’s gains and that increased consumer demand.

From 1973 to 2011, the productivity rose 80% but average compensation rose only 10%…most of that in early years. In fact, the average male worker earned the same in 2011 as they did in 1978, adjusted for inflation. At the same time the pay of CEOs went from 40 times the average compensation to 360 times. The income of the top 1% rose 6oo% over the same time.

We are told the virtuous circle no longer works because the world is flat due to competition. We are told we need to give the wealth to the rich because they are the job creators. Don’t believe it. The job creators are the middle class consumers. Companies are sitting on $2 trillion of capital. The problem isn’t shortage of capital, it is shortage of demand. The world may be flat but Germany raised their wages five times faster than us. They have built a surplus while we went into deficit and they have twice as high a proportion of their population in manufacturing.

How income gets divvied up does matter. As a long-term shareowner, I want more of the wealth going to workers so that we get out of this economic funk that is hurting us all.

, , , , , , , , , , , , , ,

Comments are closed.

Powered by WordPress. Designed by WooThemes